Tuesday , November 30 2021
Home / Peterson Institute / What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

Summary:
Economists have long relied on measures of slack, like the unemployment rate, to predict variables like the inflation rate or nominal wage growth. This analysis investigates three questions: First, what was the best univariate predictor of changes in wage or price growth in the United States over the roughly two decades prior to the pandemic? Second, which measures of wage or price growth are most predictable? And third, how might the answers to these two questions be changing in the current circumstances and going forward? Based on performance prior to the pandemic, both prime-age (25-54) nonemployment and total unemployment are slightly better predictors of wage growth, but the ratio of unemployed-to-job openings also works reasonably well and is the best predictor of core Consumer Price

Topics:
Jason Furman, Wilson Powell III considers the following as important:

This could be interesting, too:

Paul Krugman writes What Europe Can Teach Us About Jobs

conversableeconomist writes Some Economics of Place Effects

FT Alphaville writes Is a BoE rate hike off the cards?

FT Alphaville writes China’s population is shrinking, fast

Economists have long relied on measures of slack, like the unemployment rate, to predict variables like the inflation rate or nominal wage growth. This analysis investigates three questions: First, what was the best univariate predictor of changes in wage or price growth in the United States over the roughly two decades prior to the pandemic? Second, which measures of wage or price growth are most predictable? And third, how might the answers to these two questions be changing in the current circumstances and going forward? Based on performance prior to the pandemic, both prime-age (25-54) nonemployment and total unemployment are slightly better predictors of wage growth, but the ratio of unemployed-to-job openings also works reasonably well and is the best predictor of core Consumer Price Index (CPI) inflation. Today, these measures of slack are telling very different stories about the economy. The unemployed-to-job openings ratio, which has indicated much more tightness than other measures of slack, has been most consistent with recent fast wage growth and inflation and should get meaningful weight in judgments about the future of labor markets and price growth.

The predictor: Measures of labor market tightness

Originally, the Phillips curve was based on the relationship between unemployment and wage growth—when the unemployment rate is lower, wage growth is higher or rising or above its expected value (depending on the version of the Phillips curve). In recent years, economists have explored the relationship between wage growth and inflation and a wide range of alternative measures of slack including short-term unemployment and the prime-age employment rate (which reflects changes both to unemployment and labor force participation). There has been resurgent interest in looking at measures that include information from the employer side, such as the ratio of unemployed to job openings, to assess labor market tightness.

In our analysis we examine three different predictors: the headline unemployment rate (or U-3), the prime-age nonemployment rate (this is one minus the more familiar prime-age employment-to-population ratio so that lower is consistent with a tighter labor market), and the ratio of unemployed to job openings. In the roughly two-decade period prior to the pandemic (the longest period for which all three measures of slack we consider are available) these different predictors largely moved together closely as shown in figure 1, which rescales them to ensure they all have the same mean and standard deviation for ease of comparison. While there are some differences, for example, prime-age nonemployment recovered more slowly following the Great Recession of 2007-2009 than the other measures, the overall trends are very similar. This general similarity in movements means that in normal times they make the same broad predictions.

Lately, however, the three predictors have behaved very differently, giving rise to renewed interest in distinguishing between them. In particular, the ratio of unemployed workers to job openings is the lowest on record and would predict rapid wage and price growth over the next year. In contrast, the prime-age nonemployment rate is almost exactly at its average for our sample period, predicting normal wage and price growth. The unemployment rate is between these two.

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

The predicted: Consequences of labor market tightness

The Phillips curve has been used to predict both inflation and wage growth. Some aspects of price inflation, like energy prices, are largely determined by global factors that are not tightly related to labor market tightness in the United States. As a result, it is more useful to use labor market slack to predict core inflation, which excludes the relatively volatile and more internationally determined food and energy categories, rather than overall inflation. Additionally, these international concerns are likely less of a concern when using measures of domestic labor market slack to predict measures of domestic labor market performance, such as nominal wage growth, real wage growth, or the degree to which real wage growth exceeds productivity growth (i.e., real unit labor costs).

These different metrics of the consequences of labor market tightness are relatively noisy and often have behaved very differently from each other over the last 20 years as shown in figure 2.

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

Assessing these different metrics in two prediction models

We assess the different predictors in two different Phillips curve models. The first is a traditional  Phillips curve that relates current measures of slack to changes in prices or wages over the next year. This model gives rise to a permanent tradeoff between unemployment (or other measures of slack) and inflation (or other measures of the consequences of slack). This may be most appropriate when inflation expectations are very stable. The second is an autoregressive Phillips curve that effectively treats inflation or wage growth expectations as varying over time. The equations for these two are:

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

We estimate these models using measures of slack from 2001, the first year all three measures of slack are available, through 2019 for price and wage inflation. Our sample deliberately ends before the pandemic.

The traditional Phillips curve models can be illustrated with scatterplots, which are shown here for nominal wage growth as the predicted variable with our three predictors (figure 3). All  three models work reasonably well.

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

We present results for a total of 30 models using 3 different predictors * 5 different predicted variables * two specifications. As expected, the coefficient on the lagged slack term was negative in all models for each predicted variable, except real unit labor costs, with the negative coefficient statistically significant at the 5 percent level or better in 20 of the models (the exceptions are some models for core Personal Consumption Expenditures [PCE] inflation and real Employment Cost Index [ECI] wage and salary growth).

We compare the full set of models, predictors, and predicted variables by comparing their adjusted R2s, a measure of what fraction of the variation in the predicted variable is explained by the different measures. These are shown in the table. (We also looked at a range of other variables including job openings, short-term unemployment, ECI total compensation, and average hourly earnings with similar or slightly worse results than these.)

Adjusted R2 from Phillips Curve Regressions
  Prime-age nonemployment Unemployment rate Unemployed per job opening
  Traditional
Nominal ECI - Wages and Salaries 0.71 0.69 0.55
Core CPI 0.22 0.33 0.42
Core PCE 0.09 0.07 0.05
Real ECI - Wages and Salaries (Core CPI) 0.41 0.28 0.13
Real Unit Labor Costs (Core CPI) 0.04 -0.01 -0.01
  Autoregressive
Nominal ECI - Wages and Salaries 0.75 0.70 0.65
Core CPI 0.22 0.35 0.45
Core PCE 0.08 0.07 0.05
Real ECI - Wages and Salaries (Core CPI) 0.42 0.28 0.17
Real Unit Labor Costs (Core CPI) 0.03 -0.02 -0.01
Note: Real ECI - Wages and Salaries and Real Unit Labor Costs are nominal measures deflated by core CPI price index. Prime-age nonemployment is the share of the civilian population aged 25-54 that is not employed. Unemployment rate is the U-3 unemployment rate. ECI is Employment Cost Index for civilian workers.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics and Bureau of Economic Analysis via Macrobond; authors' calculations.

A few observations on these results:

  • Across these specifications, predictive power is generally greater in models with the prime-age nonemployment rate and lower in models with the ratio of unemployed to job openings. One notable exception to this general trend is for models predicting core CPI, where the ratio of unemployed to job openings has the greatest predictive power.
  • There is generally not a large difference between these three predictor variables. All of them do a reasonably similar job of predicting over this period.
  • Wages are much more predictable than prices. Because nominal wages are more sensitive to slack than prices, the real wage is procyclical, rising more quickly when slack is low. Finally real unit labor costs are so noisy that they are effectively unpredictable in these frameworks.

How stable are the relationships between these variables?

The fact that two variables have a predictive relationship in one historical period does not necessarily mean that they will going forward. On ex ante grounds there is good reason to prefer the unemployment rate over the prime-age nonemployment rate. The unemployment rate has the advantage that for over a century it has been stationary—that is, it rises and falls but generally moves around the same range—with most of its movements related to cyclical changes in the economy. In contrast, the prime-age nonemployment rate has not been stationary, falling from 37 percent in 1948 to 20 percent in 2019 as a result of not just economic fluctuations but also structural changes like the entry of women into the workforce or the exit of men from the workforce. As a result, using prime-age nonemployment rates to make predictions out of sample may be worse if any further structural changes are affecting labor force participation.

Even though the relationship between prime-age nonemployment and wages works well in the 18 years prior to 2019, it works very badly over a longer period as shown in figure 4, panel a. It is possible that all of the structural shifts that have affected labor force participation rates over the previous decades have played out and that labor force participation has stabilized, but the many slow-moving structural factors that affect even prime-age participation rates over time and across countries suggest that counting on stability is risky.

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

However, despite the generally stationary nature of the unemployment rate, its relationship with wage growth also varies substantially over time as shown in figure 4, panel b. When estimated on all available data, instead of only the roughly two decades before the COVID-19 pandemic, there is essentially no measurable relationship between wage growth and the unemployment rate. While the direction of the relationship between wage growth and the unemployment rate does not reverse like it does for prime-age nonemployment, it also is clearly not stable over time. That this relationship is unstable even with a relatively stationary measure of slack like the unemployment rate suggests that substantial caution is warranted when attempting to predict future wage or price growth.

In addition to the general concerns about the stability of these relationships over time, economists have also raised questions about how well jobs openings data capture employers' true demand for workers. Employers may have an active job posting because they are seeking to hire someone imminently, but they may also have a job posting because they might want to hire someone at some point in the future. Over time, the average amount of employer search intensity per job opening can fluctuate, which affects the interpretation of job openings as a measure of demand for workers. There are similar fluctuations in the job search intensity of the unemployed, but a technological shift towards more online hiring raises concerns that job openings today mean something different than they did 15 years ago.

This is a reasonable concern, but we do not find much reason in the data to think that such technological shifts resulted in a unique change to the predictive relationship within our sample window for the ratio of unemployed to job openings. The intercepts and/or coefficients in the regressions change around the Great Recession across our models, and the change does not appear to be systematically larger for models that include job openings (see appendix figures). It is possible that the relationship between measured job openings and true slack will change but at least since 2001, the data show that the number of unemployed workers divided by job openings has been meaningfully predictive, something that would not be the case if the structural changes and variations in the meaning of openings over this period were particularly large.

Applying these results to the present situation

The three measures of labor market slack behaved similarly in the 18 years leading up to the pandemic but have behaved very differently this year with the prime-age nonemployment rate at its average over the roughly two decades prior to the pandemic but the ratio of unemployed to job openings indicating the tightest labor market on record. This presents the sharpest test of potential differences in the properties of these predictors, albeit one that is heavily confounded by all of the other changes happening as the US economy emerges from the pandemic.

Over the last six months nominal wage and price inflation have both been very high, with ECI wages and salaries growing at a 3.4 percent annual rate (compared with a 2.4 percent annual rate in the 18 years prior to COVID-19) and core CPI prices growing at a 3.0 percent annual rate (compared with a 1.9 percent annual rate in the 18 years prior to COVID-19). These increases are likely due, at least in part, to one-off factors that are outside of this extremely simple model, like supply chain issues and the reallocation shock associated with the pandemic. They do, however, lend some greater weight to the explanatory power of the unemployed-to-job openings model as compared with the other two.

An economist trying to predict wage or price inflation over the next year would expect it to be about average if they used the prime-age nonemployment rate, above average if they used the unemployment rate, and well above average if they used the ratio of unemployed to job  openings (which suggests the labor market is tighter than ever). So far, the unemployed-to-job openings model prediction is doing a better job making sense of what is happening—and it suggests additional pressures on prices and wages as well as faster inflation-adjusted wage growth going forward.

What is the best measure of labor market tightness?

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *