Thursday , August 22 2019
Home / Jared Bernstein: On the economy / Some responses to the responses to my “4-economic mistakes” piece.

Some responses to the responses to my “4-economic mistakes” piece.

Summary:
I got lots of interesting feedback on a piece I wrote for Vox about long-held but empirically wrong assumptions in some key areas of economics, assumptions that have been asymmetrically harmful. That is, their costs consistently fall on those with low- and moderate incomes and their benefits help the wealthy. Some argued that I didn’t go far enough. Dean Baker, a friend and frequent co-author, argued that I pulled punches regarding globalization, which “…was designed to hurt workers. We could have had globalization where we reduced IP barriers and trade in professional services (e.g. doctors).” (Baker explores such themes in his book Rigged, a close, older cousin of themes in my Vox piece.) Various respondents added other harmful policies supported by bad economics, such as Kevin Drum’s

Topics:
Jared Bernstein considers the following as important:

This could be interesting, too:

Jared Bernstein writes A quick note on China’s devaluation

Jared Bernstein writes Still a solid job market, but with a cloud or two

Jared Bernstein writes Sharing the wealth, or at least the compensation

Jared Bernstein writes Here’s a simple way to tell if someone (like the Nat’ Restaurant Assoc.) is abusing numbers to mislead.

I got lots of interesting feedback on a piece I wrote for Vox about long-held but empirically wrong assumptions in some key areas of economics, assumptions that have been asymmetrically harmful. That is, their costs consistently fall on those with low- and moderate incomes and their benefits help the wealthy.

Some argued that I didn’t go far enough. Dean Baker, a friend and frequent co-author, argued that I pulled punches regarding globalization, which “…was designed to hurt workers. We could have had globalization where we reduced IP barriers and trade in professional services (e.g. doctors).” (Baker explores such themes in his book Rigged, a close, older cousin of themes in my Vox piece.) Various respondents added other harmful policies supported by bad economics, such as Kevin Drum’s reference to supply-side tax cuts.

But the main complaint was that I was too blaming of economists, not all of whom promote these wrong ideas, and that I conflated economists and policy makers. In fact, I explicitly tried not make that conflation in the piece, which starts with arguably the most important economic official in the world, Fed chair Jerome Powell (a lawyer, not an economist, but still…), agreeing that estimates of the “natural rate” of unemployment have been too high.

On globalization, I emphasize that trade theory itself is very clear that expanded trade generates winners and losers, and explicitly tagged policymakers:

“But the theory never said expanded trade would be win-win for all. Instead, it (and its more contemporary extensions) explicitly said that expanded trade generates winners and losers, and that the latter would be our blue-collar production workers exposed to international competition. True, the theory maintained (correctly in my view) that the benefits to the winners were large enough to offset the costs to the losers and still come out ahead. But as trade between nations expanded, policymakers quickly forgot about the need to compensate for the losses.”

But I also want to be careful to not be overly exonerating. In trade debates in the 1990s, as any Economic Policy Institute veteran will tell you, pure win-win arguments, like the one I pulled out of the 1994 Economic Report of the President, dominated among economists. EPI’s arguments that elevated the plight of those hurt by trade were treated as heresy, and not just by politicians trying to pass NAFTA, but by economists. Just ask EPIers like Rob Scott, Thea Lee, and Larry Mishel, who have the scars to prove it.

On the minimum wage, I personally recall debates with economists—and such debates persist to this day (though I readily grant that there are now fewer of them)—that essentially argue “if you raise the price of something, people will buy less of it, full stop.” As Robert Cherry reveals in this survey of older textbooks, the notion that increases in minimum wages could help low-wage workers was, as I said, treated as akin to believing that water flowed uphill.

Also, the piece stressed the point that prominent, powerfully placed economists were motivated by “crowd-out” arguments in the pretty recent past.

To underscore a theme that maybe didn’t come across strongly enough, excellent, evidence-based work is throwing off many of these old chains. The piece was again explicit about the important minimum-wage analysis by economists to test the assumption that increases mostly harm their intended beneficiaries (I mention the late Alan Krueger, as he was a trailblazer, but he was far from alone). There’s been similarly important work on the folly of budget austerity, like the renown Blanchard analysis I review here. So, while I understand where my fellow econo-travelers would take umbrage (justifiably provoked by some of the writing), the point is not that every economist always makes these mistakes. It’s that these mistakes were, and in some cases, still are, made with high frequency, and at great cost. There’s even a credible argument that the denial of trade’s downsides helped elect Trump, especially when you consider how the geography of the electoral college intersects with the people and places most hurt by expanded, imbalanced trade.

Something else I didn’t emphasize enough is that none of these relationships is etched in stone. The Phillips Curve could steepen (i.e., the negative correlation between unemployment and inflation could revive); excessive public borrowing could push up interest rates; it’s of course possible to set the minimum wage too high. The key economic point of the piece is that these, and every other asserted relationship in economics, must constantly be empirically evaluated. (The “constantly” is important. Elasticities change over time.)

The key political point is that the first-order assumptions I challenge invariably support capital over labor, and that this power bias is a big reason such bad economics persist, even in the face of better economics.

Finally, a few people asked what we should do in the four areas upon which I focused. I’ve written reams about that and don’t have the patience to dig up links. But on estimates of the too-high natural rate, the key is to be evidence-based, as was/is the practice of the Yellen/Powell Fed. Absent price/wage pressures, realized and expected, it’s hard to make a convincing case that actual unemployment is below the “natural rate.” On globalization, I’ve written tons on ideas to help, some of which I tick off in the piece. On austerity, see the link above re the Blanchard piece re good debt, bad debt. On the minimum wage…raise it!

Jared Bernstein
Jared Bernstein joined the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities in May 2011 as a Senior Fellow. From 2009 to 2011, Bernstein was the Chief Economist and Economic Adviser to Vice President Joe Biden, Executive Director of the White House Task Force on the Middle Class, and a member of President Obama’s economic team. Prior to joining the Obama administration, Bernstein was a senior economist and the director of the Living Standards Program at the Economic Policy Institute, and between 1995 and 1996, he held the post of Deputy Chief Economist at the U.S. Department of Labor.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *