The "curse of knowledge" refers to a bias documented in various psychology and behavioral economics studies. Once you know something, it can be hard to remember what it was like before you knew it, or to put yourself in the shoes of someone who doesn't know it. It's a barrier to communication.Iwo Hwerka provides a short readable overview of some of the evidence behind "the curse of knowledge at the "Towards Data Science" blog (November 26, 2019). For example, one study asked a group of experience salespeople how long it would take an novice to learn to do certain tasks with a cellphone: their estimate were about twice as long as it actually took. One aspect of the curse of knowledge is what psychologists sometimes call "hindsight bias." Say that you make a prediction, and later events
Topics:
Timothy Taylor considers the following as important:
This could be interesting, too:
Global Economic Intersection Analysis Blog Feed writes Double Dip Recession?
Global Economic Intersection Analysis Blog Feed writes The Post-Keynesian View Of Monetary Policy
Tyler Cowen writes Scott Alexander’s Substack
Tyler Cowen writes That was then, this is now, now it’s now again
Fischhoff and Ruth Beyth refer to this pattern as "creeping determinism," by which they mean that once something has happened, we can't readily imagine it not happening. Scholars of events like wars (say, the US Civil War or World War II) or election outcomes often tend to emphasize that the outcome was not preordained. It could have gone the other way. There was an element of chance involved in the outcome. But once the event has happened, for many of us the nuance quickly falls away, and it becomes easy to explain--with the operation of full 20:20 hindsight--why the outcome that happened was really almost certain to happen all along.
The label of this bias seems to have originated in a 1989 Journal of Political Economy article, "The Curse of Knowledge in Economic Settings: An Experimental Analysis," by Colin Camerer, George Loewenstein, and Martin Weber. They write that the term was suggested to them by Robin Hogarth. Their article is focused on a point that will immediately have occurred to economists: in most models, a party with more knowledge can in some way benefit from that knowledge over the party with less knowledge. But the curse of knowledge seems to suggest that the party with more knowledge won't be able to imagine not having that knowledge, and thus will not benefit from it (or at least will not benefit as much as expected).
I once attended a lecture on biology addressed to a large general audience at a conference on technology, entertainment and design. The lecture was also being filmed for distribution over the Internet to millions of other laypeople. The speaker was an eminent biologist who had been invited to explain his recent breakthrough in the structure of DNA. He launched into a jargon-packed technical presentation that was geared to his fellow molecular biologists, and it was immediately apparent to everyone in the room that none of them understood a word and he was wasting their time. Apparent to everyone, that is, except the eminent biologist. When the host interrupted and asked him to explain the work more clearly, he seemed genuinely surprised and not a little annoyed. This is the kind of stupidity I am talking about. Call it the Curse of Knowledge: a difficulty in imagining what it is like for someone else not to know something that you know.Haven't we all been an audience of that kind, at one time or another? Maybe it was an academic lecture. Maybe it was your car mechanic telling you what was wrong with the engine, or your neighbor explaining their gardening tips, or a distant relative explaining their job to you. Pinker also writes:
The curse of knowledge is the single best explanation of why good people write bad prose. It simply doesn't occur to the writer that her readers don't know what she knows--that they haven't mastered the argot of her guild, can't divine the missing steps that seem too obvious to mention, have no way to visualize a scene that to her is as clear as day. And so the writer doesn't bother to explain the jargon, or spell out the logic, or supply the necessary detail.My guess is that the curse of knowledge goes well beyond these settings, and causes problems in all kind of communications between specialists in one area and others. In many companies, the communications between engineers and marketing departments is fraught with misunderstandings. When doctors and patients interact, can doctors really remember what it was like not to know about symptoms and health conditions?